• IP addresses are NOT logged in this forum so there's no point asking. Please note that this forum is full of homophobes, racists, lunatics, schizophrenics & absolute nut jobs with a smattering of geniuses, Chinese chauvinists, Moderate Muslims and last but not least a couple of "know-it-alls" constantly sprouting their dubious wisdom. If you believe that content generated by unsavory characters might cause you offense PLEASE LEAVE NOW! Sammyboy Admin and Staff are not responsible for your hurt feelings should you choose to read any of the content here.

    The OTHER forum is HERE so please stop asking.

Keynes and the puzzle of falling prices

winnipegjets

Alfrescian (Inf)
Asset
Keynes and the puzzle of falling prices

Benign disinflation means rising real incomes for lenders, pensioners, and workers - but ‘bad deflation’ means an increase in the real burden of debt

In 1923, John Maynard Keynes addressed a fundamental economic question that remains valid today. “nflation is unjust and deflation is inexpedient,” he wrote. “Of the two perhaps deflation is … the worse; because it is worse…to provoke unemployment than to disappoint the rentier. But it is not necessary that we should weigh one evil against the other.”

The logic of the argument seems irrefutable. Because many contracts are “sticky” (that is, not easily revised) in monetary terms, inflation and deflation would both inflict damage on the economy. Rising prices reduce the value of savings and pensions, while falling prices reduce profit expectations, encourage hoarding, and increase the real burden of debt.

Keynes’s dictum has become the ruling wisdom of monetary policy (one of his few to survive). Governments, according to the conventional wisdom, should aim for stable prices, with a slight bias toward inflation to stimulate the “animal spirits” of businessmen and shoppers.

In the 10 years prior to the 2008 financial crisis, independent central banks set an inflation target of about 2%, in order to provide economies with a price-stability “anchor”. There should be no expectation that prices would be allowed to deviate, except temporarily, from the target. Uncertainty relating to the future course of prices would be eliminated from business calculations.

Since 2008, the Federal Reserve Board and the European Central Bank have failed to meet the 2% inflation target in any year; the Bank of England (BoE) has been on target in only one year out of seven. Moreover, in 2015, prices in the United States, the eurozone, and the United Kingdom are set to fall. So what is left of the inflation anchor? And what do falling prices mean for economic recovery?

The first thing to bear in mind is that the “anchor” was always as flimsy as the monetary theory on which it was based. The price level at any time is the result of many factors, of which monetary policy is perhaps the least important. Today, the collapse in the price of crude oil is probably the most significant factor driving inflation below target, just as in 2011 it was the rise in oil prices that drove it above target.

As British economist Roger Bootle pointed out in his 1996 book The Death of Inflation, the price-cutting effects of globalisation have been a much more important influence on the price level than the anti-inflation policies of central banks. Indeed, the post-crisis experience of quantitative easing has highlighted monetary policy’s relative powerlessness to offset the global deflationary trend. From 2009 to 2011, the BoE pumped £375bn into the British economy “to bring inflation back to target.” The Fed injected $3tn over a slightly longer period. The most that can be claimed for this vast monetary expansion is that it produced a temporary “spike” in inflation.

The old adage applies: “You can lead a horse to water, but you can’t make it drink.” People cannot be forced to spend money if they have good reasons for not doing so. If business prospects are weak, companies are unlikely to invest; if households are drowning in debt, they are unlikely to go on a spending spree. The ECB is about to discover the truth of this as it starts on its own €1tn programme of monetary expansion in an effort to stimulate the stagnant eurozone economy.

So what happens to the recovery if we fall into what is euphemistically called “negative inflation”? Until now, the consensus view has been that this would be bad for output and employment. Keynes gave the reason in 1923: “the fact of falling prices,” he wrote, “injures entrepreneurs; consequently the fear of falling prices causes them to protect themselves by curtailing their operations.”

But many commentators have been cheered by the prospect of falling prices. They distinguish between “benign disinflation” and “bad deflation.” Benign disinflation means rising real incomes for lenders, pensioners, and workers, and falling energy prices for industry. All sectors of the economy will spend more, pushing up output and employment (and sustaining the price level, too).

By contrast, “bad deflation” means an increase in the real burden of debt. A debtor contracts to pay a fixed sum in interest every year. If the value of money goes up (prices fall), the interest he pays will cost him more, in terms of goods and services he can buy, than if prices had stayed the same. (In the reverse, inflationary case, the interest will cost him less.) Thus, price deflation means debt inflation; and a higher debt burden means lower spending. Given the huge levels of outstanding private and public debt, bad deflation, as Bootle writes, “is a nightmare almost beyond imagining.”

But how can we stop benign disinflation from turning into bad deflation? Apostles of monetary expansion believe that all you have to do is speed up the printing press. But why should this be any more successful in the future than it has been in the last few years?

Avoiding deflation – and thus sustaining economic recovery – would seem to depend on one of two scenarios: either a rapid reversal in the fall of energy prices, or a deliberate policy to raise output and employment by means of public investment (which, as a byproduct, would bring about a rise in prices). But this would mean reversing the priority given to deficit reduction.

No one can tell when the first will happen; and no governments are prepared to do the second. So the most likely outcome is more of the same: continued drift in a state of semi-stagnation.

Robert Skidelsky, a member of the British House of Lords, is Professor Emeritus of Political Economy at Warwick University.
 

Asterix

Alfrescian (Inf)
Asset
Sing Dollar drop to 1.75 and savings deposit rate at say 4% will make me very happy. :smile:

Deflation is not all bad news for consumers and businesses
The "cost-push" effect from falling oil prices has seen more money spent on goods and services and may have wider implications for growth

Deflation is the stuff of nightmares for central bankers. The dread of falling consumer prices and negative inflation has spurred major central banks into taking unprecedented steps in recent years to stop sliding prices from turning into deeper economic turmoil.

Deflation gets very bad press as something unfamiliar to most of us and is often portrayed as an affliction to be feared. Sure enough, it can pose huge challenges for policymakers, but it is not all bad news. There are times when deflation can offer positive spin-offs for consumers and businesses, which can also have better implications for growth.

"Bad" deflation happens in times of severe economic duress, when weak demand has a downward drag on prices for goods and services. It is known as "demand-pull" deflation, which can spin out of control when economic confidence is at a very low ebb.

Consumers and businesses can be put off spending and investment in the hope of getting better deals in the future. This delayed spending sets off a chain reaction of weaker demand and more price-cutting, leading to a downward spiral of deep recession.

The worst case of severe demand-pull deflation is evident in Greece where the economy has lost 25 per cent of national output in recent years and domestic prices have collapsed, thanks to very tough austerity conditions. Consumer inflation is still stuck at minus 2.8 per cent now.

It was the fear of these trends getting a grip at the height of the financial crisis that drove the US Federal Reserve and the Bank of England into quantitative easing programmes. And it is the motivation behind recent decisions by the European Central Bank and Sweden's Riksbank to adopt quantitative easing to stop deflation getting out of control.

There are times when deflation can have a very positive effect. The dramatic collapse in global oil prices over the past six months has triggered an unanticipated "cost-push" deflation effect in the major economies due to lower energy and fuel costs. Consumers and businesses have more money to spend on other goods and services. For economies like the US and Britain, where consumer demand dominates gross domestic product, there are clear upside implications for stronger growth.
Right now, equity markets are starting to wake up to the potential growth dividend effect of cost-push deflation.
In Britain last week, when consumer price index inflation hit an historic 0.3 per cent low, it was met with a positive reaction by British stocks. With unemployment tailing off very sharply in the past few years and average wage rises outpacing inflation, it means real disposable incomes are on the way up and the squeeze on consumers is coming to an end.

Policymakers around the world need to be very clear about what kind of deflation they are dealing with or bad policy mistakes will be made. A distinction needs to be made about causality and whether falling prices are being "demand-led" or "cost-pushed".

The US and British economies are both enjoying multiyear recovery cycles, but worries about the potential risk of deflation are having a bearing on the expected timing for normalising monetary policy in the future. The Fed is beginning to fret about raising interest rates too soon, given downside inflation risks. The Bank of England is intimating the possibility that rate rises may be delayed until next year, thanks to the deepening spectre of deflation in Britain.

Delaying rate tightening may be a strategic error if sticking with over-accommodative policy means both central banks end up over-egging the recovery.

While the US and British economies were staring into the jaws of demand-pull deflation and economic doom in 2008, the circumstances look very different today. The current disinflation tide is thanks to a one-off exogenous shock - lower oil prices. If global oil prices stabilise and recover quickly, the central banks could be blighted by a double whammy of rising cost-push and demand-led inflation risks ahead if rate settings are too low. There is a strong argument to stick to earlier policy normalisation intentions.

David Brown is the chief executive of New View Economics

http://www.scmp.com/business/econom...ion-not-all-bad-news-consumers-and-businesses
 
Top